Volume 2, Number 54
12 September 2002

Good Fences Make Good Neighbors (Robert Frost)

Dear Friends,

Fences (real or imagined) tell the world whose apples grow on whose trees, who mows whose lawns, and who has a right to invite friends to a garden party. When the neighbors recognize each other's rights and obligations, they are good neighbors. Then they cooperate on mosquito control and other aspects of community interest.

You have to know who you are, yourself, if you wish to reach out to others, psychologists tell us.

Is it the same in economics? For many centuries, the Western World has been erecting fences not only between property owners, but also between laborers, capitalists, boards of directors, accountants, and governments. Once they all know who they are, and what are their rights and privileges, they learn to cooperate.

Some fences have been broken down lately, as when Arthur Andersen and Enron did not know where the fence stood — or should have stood — between them.

One can, of course, be both laborer and capitalist, property owner and accountant, and so on. But if so, one must know one's rights and privileges in the capacity of each, without mixing them. Then the laborer may cooperate with the capitalist, and others as well.

We all cooperate in a free market society. The shirt I wear was bought in the USA, but it was made in Taiwan, possibly with cotton grown in Australia and woven in China. I don't know the various steps, but I do know that free people trade this way. When a job is offered at a given wage, the worker has a right to refuse, and seek employment elsewhere. Likewise, each material is sold at an agreed price; and I buy the shirt at the price the seller states. If I don't like the price, I don't buy.

There are those whose circumstances give them little or no choice. They eke out a scant living on a farm in Mexico or Africa, etc., and do not have the funds to seek betterment in the city. For these, I favor a cash subsidy, where the public purse supplements their earnings for a minimal living, plus the possibility of seeking something better. But let them keep their fences.

Fallacies of Non-Fencists

The ideal of communism was a non-fencist state. Laborers would make products for the sheer joy of doing so and would gladly share them with consumers, who would not take more than they needed. As it turned out, workers lagged on the job when they were not paid, and some consumers wanted more than others thought they should. The organization of this society — say, the Soviet Union — required the coercion to tell laborers what to produce and consumers what they might buy. But power breeds greed, and soon the entire society was dominated by a few decision-makers who did not (could not) make the proper decisions to create an abundant society (see TQE #49). When the Soviet Union found its economy far behind the West, with starvation on some collective farms, a shift in direction became imperative.

Many good people today believe that fences should be torn down because they divide us. Here are some of the proposals I heard on a radio talk show in which I recently participated, followed by my comment:

(1) Employees should own their companies. The very people who make the product should sell it and receive the profit.

Why not? Well, because often they do not think up the product, nor do they supply the capital. Those who innovate frisbees or come up with the cash to produce them think they have more rights over size, shape, and how to market them than the helpers they hire. Are they right to think they should control the process, with employees accepting their terms or looking for jobs elsewhere?

Employee ownership works just fine in small enterprises, like Moosewood Cookbook, in which friends get together to produce something. But, small or large, if the company in which you work and invest goes belly-up, you lose both your life savings and your job. Better to build a fence between them.

In large companies, it is different. United Airlines boasts of being "employee owned." True. But the employees cannot all sit on the board of directors, nor do pilots and stewardesses have experience reading balance sheets. So, they hire a professional board of directors, which hires professional management. Recently, management has considered bankruptcy as a result of 9/11 losses. The employee unions do not want that. Who decides? The directors, of course, after listening to the unions. If the owners/employees do not like the directors' decisions, they can fire the board. If they do that, however, they have to find another board, probably one not much different from the one they just fired.

Whatever they decide, the employees, board, and management must cooperate or the planes will not fly.

(2) Company books should be open.

There is good reason for this. It might have prevented the Enron, World.Com, etc. scandals. But it would also allow competitors to see what you are planning, and if so, you might be less inclined to innovate. Would we have computers and software today if others had looked over the shoulders of the inventors all along?

(3) Labor-based political involvement ought to represent the political interests of labor, which is usually the underdog.

Many countries have this. In Argentina, for example, the Ministry of Labor negotiates and enforces agreements between workers and management. (Anyone want to work in Argentina?) By my sights, labor-based political involvement creates the class society that its backers want to avoid. By winner deciding issues, instead of both negotiating them, it drives a wedge of "them against us," as opposed to a fence, which teaches us our identities but over which we can speak to each other.

BTW: The Labour Party in Britain (and the Labor Party in Australia) no longer represent Labor. The name is just a hangover from earlier days when labor-based political involvement was thought to be fruitful.

(4) Boards of Directors should be open to all stakeholders, who are all those who have some stake in the company: workers, customers, suppliers, stockholders, and others. They should not be selected by stockholders alone.

This high case of non-fencism has been tried in Germany and Yugoslavia. Unfortunately, the interests of each group were so different that they harmed the company for their own benefit. In Yugoslavia, workers milked the companies into bankruptcy. Finally, the country fell apart. German boards have mandated such extraordinary sick leave, vacations, and terminal pay that management has tried to get along with fewer workers, using machines instead. Finally, Germany has retreated from being the lead economic power in Europe to becoming a secondary player.

People cooperate in an endeavor (say, Enron) so long as the success of the endeavor is more meaningful to them than what they can individually get out of it if they destroy it. The experiences of Argentina, Germany, and Enron, etc., have taught us that a corporation is successful only if adequate fences are maintained between stakeholders.

(5) We should strive for a society of equality in income and wealth.

This is a tough one. I could be much more wealthy than I am, if I had stayed with business or government. But I like teaching, so I preferred that career. Many say that when we have enough, we should not want more. When I started at the University of Colorado, I was the highest paid professor in the Department of Economics. Then others, more distinguished than I, were brought in at higher salaries. I had the choice of being jealous or accepting them as role models. "Equality" was not an option.

Do we (or should we) have equality in other aspects of life? Sports, for instance. Should we abolish baseball, football, and the Olympics, because they encourage some to be better than others? Should we abolish the valedictorian of the class, so as not to shame those who didn't make it? Can we strive to be the best without having to beat someone else? Can we innovate, or invent, for the sheer joy of doing so?

Many think so. But I believe that we would remove many of the joys of life and decrease our innovations if we were all the same, or pretended to be. The inventor of the steam engine, the automobile, the computer, want to think of themselves as bringing society something better than it had before. They also want to be rewarded. How would we grow, if we did not have role models better than we are? How would we live, if we did not learn how to accept defeat?

There are only so many places for the freshman class in Swarthmore each year. Those not accepted must learn that not going to Swarthmore is not the end of the world. There is always the University of Colorado (actually, a pretty good place, I have found).

But, what about the economic system? Can we allow some to be richer than others? Well, Europe and its cultural descendents, and Japan, that have enjoyed the most freedom of enterprise and have put fewer barriers on trade than have others, are the very ones that have reached the greatest prosperity and the most egalitarian distributions of income. They have done so by each person knowing who he or she is, by innovating and saving, and by all knowing they can bargain freely. Then inventors freely take their products to capitalists, and together they become innovators. New technology is discovered in a world of both fences and cooperation. Innovators are rich at first, but the wealth spreads over time. (Yes, they also used slaves, but innovation was far more compelling than slavery as a reason for development, and it even led to the end of slavery.)

(6) The free market punishes the poor.

This is another tough one. However, most economists (including me) believe the cause of poverty lies elsewhere than the free market. If the poorest of the poor, even with very limited opportunity, should be free to make their own choices — whether to stay on the farm or work in maquiladoras or sweatshops, for example — they will choose what is best for them. Better for well-meaning outsiders not to interfere with their choices, though we may help them if they ask. (We might also give them money, as I have suggested above.)

We should be very careful about assigning cause to poverty. If we guess wrong, as I believe this statement does, and then base policy decisions upon our guess, we can do great harm.

How do you feel about living in a world of fences, provided you can talk over them to the next-door neighbor?

Sincerely your friend,

Jack


Readers' Comments

Please send comments on this or any TQE, at any time. Selected comments will be appended to the appropriate letter as they are received. Please indicate in the subject line the number of the Letter to which you refer! The email address is tqe-comment followed by @quaker.org. All published letters will be edited for spelling, grammar, clarity, and brevity. Please mention your home meeting, church, synagogue (or ...), and where you live.


Fences are certainly necessary in today's world for bringing about some sort of rationality in economic life. But I'd like to believe that human beings are still evolving and could eventually reach that level of enlightenment where the Communist (and Christian, too) ideal of "From each according to his ability; to each according to his need" could become a reality for much of society. There are altruistic people in the world today, and even occasionally we hear of a business where there is real cooperation and altruism at all levels. It may be a few thousand years before we get to the point, though, for a whole economy to be based successfully on that philosophy.

— Virginia Flagg, San Diego (CA) Friends Meeting.


In a "fenced world" I think equality of income and wealth are best addressed in ones role as voter. (You fenced off Government, but not voters). You argued persuasively against mandated equality (but hinted at redistribution in giving money to peasants): However, this leaves a question as to what sort of world do we want to live in? Fiscal policy can be used to influence income inequality (taxation, especially of wealth) and promote equality of opportunity (subsidization of education). Yes there are implications for incentives, equity and even political feasibility, but these are issues deserving your precise analysis.

— Wilfred Candler, Annapolis (MD) Friends Meeting.


Is there any justification why anyone should receive 4x more than the average or 4x less than the average? Is anyone that valuable or that worthless? Wealth and income involve all aspects of oneâs life as well as the lives of oneâs family.

— Roger Benham, Smithers, BC, Canada.


ABOUT TQE

RSVP: Write to "tqe-comment," followed by "@quaker.org" to comment on this or any future Letter. (I say "followed by" to interrupt the address, so it will not be picked up by spam senders.) Use as Subject the number of the Letter to which you refer. Permission to publish your comment is presumed unless you say otherwise. Please keep it short. Letters will be edited for spelling, grammar, clarity, and brevity. Any letter over approximately 100 words may be returned without being read. Please mention your home meeting, church, or synagogue, if any (this is not required), and your location.

To subscribe or unsubscribe at no cost, please visit our Home Page.

Each letter of The Quaker Economist is copyright by its author. However, you have permission to forward it to your friends (Quaker or no) as you wish and invite them to subscribe at no cost. Please mention The Quaker Economist as you do so, and tell your recipient how to find it.

The Quaker Economist is not designed to persuade anyone of anything, although viewpoints are expressed. Its purpose is to stimulate discussions, both electronically and within Meetings.

Publisher and Editorial Board

Publisher: Russ Nelson, St. Lawrence Valley (NY) Friends Meeting

Editorial Board:

  • Roger Conant, Mount Toby Meeting, Leverett (MA).
  • Carol Conzelman, Boulder (CO).
  • Ann Dixon, Boulder (CO) Friends Meeting.
  • Virginia Flagg, San Diego (CA) Friends Meeting.
  • Merlyn Holmes, Unitarian, Boulder, Colorado.
  • Janet Minshall, Anneewakee Creek Friends Worship Group, Douglasvillle (GA).
  • Jack Powelson, Boulder (CO) Meeting of Friends, Principal Editor
  • J.D. von Pischke, a Friend from Reston, VA.
  • Geoffrey Williams, Attender at New York Fifteenth Street Meeting.

Members of the Editorial Board receive Letters several days in advance for their criticisms, but they do not necessarily endorse the contents of any of them.


Copyright © 2002 by John P. Powelson. All rights reserved. Permission is hereby granted for non-commercial reproduction.


Previous Letter | Home Page | Next Letter